Menu

Ghana: Capitalism for the Rest of Us

Fri, 24 Jul 2015 Source: Kwarteng, Francis

“Politics and governance are more important to theoretical economics, or, we must love truly anarchy,” notes Prof. Lungu. “Government matters, that is, the use of government power matters. The right wing in America would want us all to behave as if ‘depressions (are) acts of God," unless, it is to their benefit in subsidies, free interest rates, free money in property values made possible by government regulation, and zero payment of taxes, among them Social Security taxes.”

These observations ate statements of facts born of experience. State or government intervention in specific cases has made the market better. No less the works of John Maynard Keynes and those of Adam Smith, “the father of modern economics,” categorically make a strong case for state or government in specific instances as essential to making market mechanism operate freely.

In this connection, the idea that Smith was a doctrinaire or dogmatic opponent of state or government intervention is a blatant lie. Right-ring politics has distorted “The Wealth of Nations” to suit its agenda. In one of our upcoming articles we shall show how “The Wealth of Nations” supports state or government in specific instances.

We shall also show how Keynesian economics is used around the world (in every single economy in the world), both in the 20th and 21st centuries, including how the Asian Tigers or the emerging Asian economies built their success stories partly on the strength of Keynesian economics. Our working title is “What Ghanaians Can Learn from Pope Francis.” Watch out!

In sum, those who claim Keynesian economics is dead have no clear what is going on around them. The following four are illustrative of how Keynesian Economics is being used today:

1) “Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke: The Brain Behind Quantitative Easing” (Source: Forbes)

2) “China’s Central Bank to Implement Quantitative Easing to Boost Slowing Economy: Report (Source: International Business Times)

3) “Japan’s Quantitative Easing” (Source: The Economist)

4) “Europe Quantitative Easing” (Source: Financial Times)

Next, the article below shows how some of America’s Founding Fathers wanted to distribute wealth and profit among their citizens, including forcibly taking lands from Native Americans and freely giving them away to Europeans, among others, and how some contemporary American researchers and politicians are making a case for profit-sharing as one of many steps to reduce America’s rising inequality.

Thus, we could probably understand why those decisions (slavery, forcible land seizure, etc) by some members of America’s Founding Fathers contributed to the development of American capitalism!

Are these proposals socialism or capitalism? We do not know. We leave it up to readers to decide. Yet they sound more Keynesian than Smithian though “The Wealth of Nations” influenced the Founding Fathers. One also learns from the article that state or government intervention had been part and parcel of the market right from the founding of the American Republic. This is not necessarily antithetical to the central tenets of “The Wealth of Nations.”

Everything aside, we cannot help but agree with Prof. Lungu when he said: “Ghana, there is more socialism in America for the ‘right people,’ than there is capitalism in Switzerland, Holland, etc., for all the people.” Of course, there is also more socialism in America for the “right people” than there is capitalism in Ghana (and Africa). Please read on:

Authors: Joseph R. Blasi, Richard B. Freeman, and Douglas L. Kruse.

Title: Capitalism for the Rest of Us

Source: The New York Times (July 17, 2015)

IN her most detailed economic policy address so far, Hillary Rodham Clinton said Monday that she wanted “to give workers the chance to share in the profits they help produce” through a two-year tax credit that would encourage profit-sharing. As social scientists who have studied the issue for years, we were glad to see it get attention.

The stagnation of earnings for most Americans, despite rising productivity, and the shrinkage of the middle class, because of soaring inequality, are without precedent in our economic history.

Capital’s share of national income has risen, while labor’s share has fallen—even though it includes lavish compensation of executives who are paid disproportionately through stock grants, options and bonuses. To restore prosperity for all, we need to spread the benefits of economic growth to entrepreneurial citizens through profit-sharing and the ownership of capital. This isn’t some radical notion; it has a long tradition in America.

Many of the founders believed that the best economic plan for the republic was for citizens to own land, which was then the main form of productive capital.

Washington signed into law tax credits to help revive the cod fishery destroyed by the British during the revolution, requiring that everyone had a share in the profits, from the cabin boy to the captain. The Northwest Ordinance of 1787 offered land cheaply to settlers. Jefferson concluded the Louisiana Purchase in 1803 to help further the notion of “an empire of liberty” through broad land ownership. Lincoln’s landmark Homestead Act of 1862 gave federal land grants to settlers. (As a result of the Civil War, it was passed without representatives of the South, where land was concentrated in the hands of slaveholders.)

As America industrialized in the late 19th century, the economy became dominated by big corporations. And yet some family-run businesses, and entrepreneurs who were concerned about the place of workers in an economy dominated by gigantic enterprises, sought to extend the benefits of capitalism to employees. Companies like Pillsbury, Kodak and Procter & Gamble introduced widespread profit-sharing and employee stock ownership.

The economic boom after World War II solidified the view that regular increases in fixed wages and benefits could carry the burden of “sharing the wealth.” Sadly, since the 1970s, wages have stagnated, and the idea of profit-sharing has been largely forgotten in public debates.

It’s time to revive it. The United States already has more extensive profit-sharing and employee share ownership than many other advanced economies. In the European Union in 2010, fewer than 10 percent of workers own company stock and fewer than 30 percent have profit-sharing (except Sweden, where the figure is 36 percent).

In the United States last year, close to 20 percent of private-sector employees owned stock, and 7 percent held stock options, in the companies where they worked, while about one-third participated in some kind of cash profit-sharing and one-fourth in gain-sharing (when workers get additional compensation based on improvement on a metric other than profits, like sales or customer satisfaction). An exemplar was Southwest Airlines, which paid $355 million of its more than $1 billion in corporate profits last year to union and nonunion workers and managers, on top of salaries.

Our research found that these programs, when combined with worker participation in solving problems, and increased training and job security, raise productivity and benefit workers. In every year, about half the winners in Fortune’s list of 100 Best Companies to Work For have some type of broad-based profit or gain-sharing or stock ownership for regular workers. Google, Intel and Starbucks all have broad-based stock grants or options for their employees. Wegmans has profit-sharing. W. L. Gore, the maker of Gore-Tex, and Publix Super Markets, which operates in the Southeast, are owned by employee stock ownership plans, wherein a workers’ trust typically borrows money to buy shares that are paid out of company revenues.

Some scholars have worried that employee-share ownership is too risky when workers buy the stock with their wages or 401(k) retirement savings; Enron is the classic example. We agree. We favor only ownership policies that emphasize grants of stock (as in the case of employee stock-ownership plans), restricted stock (which has to be held on to for a certain period of time, incentivizing workers to stay) or stock options.

How do we achieve this? First, the notion needs more powerful advocates from business and politics, like Mrs. Clinton. In New Jersey, lawmakers are finalizing legislation to expand tax incentives for small-business owners to sell their businesses to their employees and managers; Iowa has adopted similar legislation.

Second, we need to reform a little-known tax loophole, Section 162(m), of the Internal Revenue Code. In the early 1990s, in an attempt to reform executive pay, Congress changed that section to limit corporate income tax deductions to $1 million for the top five executive salaries, but allowed virtually unlimited deductions for a variety of top-executive performance-based pay, including equity and profit-sharing. Corporations, which have exploited this loophole to offer lavish compensation packages, should get these deductions only if they offer a profit-sharing or share-ownership plan to all employees.

Finally, all levels of government—federal, state and local—should offer incentives to companies that implement profit-sharing and employee-share ownership. Such incentives should include tax breaks, tax incentives and preference in the awarding of government contracts.

Spreading around profit-sharing and the ownership of capital is not the only answer to solving the challenge of soaring inequality in America, but it’s a critical step that will help rather than hurt economic performance. If the middle class is to survive, we must move toward a more inclusive capitalism.

We shall return…

Columnist: Kwarteng, Francis