Opinions

News

Sports

Business

Entertainment

GhanaWeb TV

Africa

Country

Should government continue to subsidise fuel?

Mon, 11 Aug 2014 Source: Denis, Gyeyir M.

Introduction

Crude oil is an internationally traded commodity with prices determined by external

forces of demand and supply. Governments of many developing countries attempt to

cushion the effects of crude oil price fluctuations on their citizens particularly the poor

by instituting social intervention measures common among which is the subsidisation

of refined products. A petroleum or fuel price subsidy is usually the variance between

the reference price and the actual (selling) price of the product. Depending on the

petroleum import/export position of the country, the reference price would usually be

the world market price plus the transport cost to border (import price) or world price

minus transport cost to border (export price) or the marginal cost of domestic

production. The actual or selling price refers to the ex-pump prices at which various

products are sold to final consumers. The total amount of subsidies paid by

government is estimated by a summation of the product of unit subsidy and total

units consumed per product for all subsidised products. This essay seeks to evaluate

the feasibility of continued subsidisation of fuel prices by the government of Ghana.

Should fuel subsidies be removed?

Advocates of fuel subsidies cite several reasons in favour of the continuous

application of subsidies predominantly in less developed economies. Key among

these is the objective of curtailing the adverse consequences of fuel price hikes on

poor households and promotion of social equity. Research has revealed that

although a significantly lower percentage of subsidies benefit the poor, withdrawal of

subsidies in Ghana has witnessed a decline in real income for the poorest 20% of

consumers by as much as 9.1%, the highest among five countries studied (Coady et

al. 2006). It has also been argued that since evidence shows fuel price increases are

followed by rising prices of most products and services, subsidies could be used to

reduce inflationary pressures. Fuel subsidy reforms have also been observed to

encourage poor households to switch to fuel wood thereby depleting forests and

other natural resources. Although not usually explicitly stated in the discourse on fuel

subsidies, the avoidance of labour agitations and political unpopularity often

underline the reluctance of governments to remove fuel subsidies.

Many more reasons than outlined in support of subsidies make it more expedient for

government to withdraw subsidies. The effectiveness of other social intervention

policies relative to fuel subsidies, achieving fuel consumption efficiency, reducing

government spending, mitigating the impact of climate change are some arguments

in support of subsidy reforms. A number of studies have proven that other mechanisms of achieving social equity are more effective (Coady et al. 2006; Bacon

and Kojima 2006; Beaton and Lontoh 2010; Sumedh 2011). Alternatives that have

been identified include cash transfers, coupons, smart cards, vouchers, removal or

reduction of fees and charges on social services such as health, education and

transport. Beaton and Lontoh (2010) for example observed significant successes

with the implementation of cash transfer scheme in Indonesia in 2005. In Ghana, the

removal of subsidies has a potential to drive transfers aimed at improving the

Community Health Improvement Services (CHIPS) and other healthcare services for

the poor, „Capitation Grants? and elimination of fees for government basic and

secondary schools and mass transport systems. Such programmes have been

proven to cover significantly larger proportions of the poor population in developing

countries in comparison with fuel subsidies. Evidence from five countries including

Ghana has suggested that between 75% and 85% of the total benefits from fuel

subsidies accrue to the richest 60% of the population. A separate simulation

conducted for Ghana indicated that 65% of transfers would benefit the poorest 40%

of households compared to a corresponding 40% for kerosene subsidies (IMF 2006;

Coady et al. 2006). For such alternative programs to achieve significant success

however, they need to be underpinned by effective planning, organization and

monitoring mechanisms and prevent leakage of benefits to non-targeted groups.

Removal of fuel subsidies have also been regarded as a means of attaining

consumption efficiency. In cases where tax on products such as gasoline and diesel

have been used to cross-subsidise other products like LPG and Kerosene, it has

often resulted in inefficient substitution of kerosene to adulterate diesel and gasoline.

Empirical studies have also revealed that households become less efficient in using

subsidised petroleum products (Coady et al. 2006). Smuggling of subsidised

products to neighbouring countries where prices are relatively higher has tended to

defeat the objectives of subsidies. Under extreme circumstances, subsidies have led

to acute shortage of petroleum products as a result of the inability of government to

reimburse Bulk Distribution Companies (BDCs) as recently witnessed in Ghana in

June 2014. Such inefficiencies and buying of subsidised products for unintended

purposes can be avoided through the elimination of subsidies.

High subsidies divert government spending away from more productive and

potentially more beneficial sectors. This has consistently resulted in substantial

budget deficits which could have been financed by relatively effective petroleum

taxes as demand for petroleum products is inelastic. Subsidies have imposed a

major drain on Ghana?s economy as Tema Oil Refinery (TOR) debt reached 7% of

GDP in 2002 whiles throughout 2004, 2.2 % of the country?s GDP was spent

subsidising fuel in the run-up to the general elections (Laan et al. 2010).Conclusions

From the discussions, it is evident that fuel subsidies exert a huge burden on public

expenditure but a greater chunk of the benefits accrue to high income groups, a

situation which defeats the essence of subsidisation. Removal of petroleum

subsidies would free the needed funds for social equity programmes in health,

education and transport albeit proper planning, implementation and monitoring are

essential prerequisites. These programmes not only capture large proportions of the

poor at lesser costs but also address the inefficiencies associated with subsidisation

and cross-subsidisation. An independent price-setting regime should replace fuel

subsidies but as Laan et al. (2010) observed, this “can only be as robust as the

political will behind it”.

Author: Gyeyir M. Denis

Email: gdenismwin@hotmail.com

Columnist: Denis, Gyeyir M.